pollev.com/chrismakler


Utility Maximization Subject to a Budget Constraint
Christopher Makler
Stanford University Department of Economics
Econ 50: Lecture 6
Friday
Monday
Wednesday
Preferences & Utility
Marginal Rate of Substitution
Utility Function Examples
Budget Constraints
Utility Maximization subject to a Budget Constraint
Cases when
Calculus Doesn't Work
Demand Functions and Demand Curves
Midterm I
Decomposing a Price Change into Income & Substitution Effects
Demand Curve Shifters: Complements & Substitutes
Unit I: Consumer Theory
Welcome
Week 1
Week 2
Week 3
Week 4
Cost Minimization
Choice space:
all possible options
Feasible set:
all options available to you
Optimal choice:
Your best choice(s) of the ones available to you
Constrained Optimization

Choice Space
(all colleges plus alternatives)
Feasible Set
(colleges you got into)
Your optimal choice!
Preferences
Preferences describe how the agent ranks all options in the choice space.
For example, we'll assume that you could rank all possible colleges
(and other options for what to do after high school) based upon your preferences.
Preference Ranking
Found a startup
Harvard
Stanford
Play Xbox in parents' basement
Cal
Choice space
Feasible set
Optimal
choice!
Found a startup
Stanford
Cal
Harvard
Play XBox in parents' basement
Optimal choice is the highest-ranking option in the feasible set.
The story so far, in two graphs
If we superimpose the budget line on the utility "hill" the nature of the problem becomes clear:
Question: mathematically, how does the utility change as you spend more money on good 1?
Think about what happens
when you spend another dollar on apples
Budget line
Suppose apples (good 1) cost $4/lb,
and bananas (good 2) cost $2/lb.
Approximately what is the change in your utility? Should you do this?
(and one less on bananas)
give up \({1 \over 2}\)lb of bananas
gain \({1 \over 4}\) lb apples
Think about what happens
when you spend another dollar on apples
Budget line
Suppose apples (good 1) cost \(p_1\) per pound,
and bananas (good 2) cost \(p_2\) per pound.
Approximately what is the change in your utility? Should you do this?
(and one less on bananas)
give up \({1 \over p_2}\) bananas
gain \({1 \over p_1}\) apples
"marginal utility per dollar" or "bang for your buck"
You like apples more, but they're also more expensive.
You think about spending half your money on each good:
that is, buy 6 lbs of apples (good 1) and 12 lbs of bananas (good 2). Is this optimal?
What does it mean if you get more "bang for your buck" from good 1 than good 2?
The consumer receives more utility per additional unit of good 1 than the price reflects, relative to good 2.
The consumer receives more
"bang for the buck"
(utils per dollar)
from good 1 than good 2.
Regardless of how you look at it, the consumer would be
better off moving to the right along the budget line --
i.e., consuming more of good 1 and less of good 2.
The consumer is more willing to give up good 2
to get good 1
than the market requires.
You like apples more, but they're also more expensive.
You think about spending half your money on each good:
that is, buy 6 lbs of apples (good 1) and 12 lbs of bananas (good 2). Is this optimal?
at (6,12)...
IF...
THEN...
The consumer's preferences are "well behaved"
-- smooth, strictly convex, and strictly monotonic
\(MRS=0\) along the horizontal axis (\(x_2 = 0\))
The budget line is a simple straight line
The optimal consumption bundle will be characterized by two equations:
More generally: the optimal bundle may be found using the Lagrange method
\(MRS \rightarrow \infty\) along the vertical axis (\(x_1 \rightarrow 0\))
How do you tell if a preferences are "well behaved"?
Strictly monotonic
Strictly convex
Smooth
\(MU_1 > 0\) and \(MU_2 > 0\) for any \(x_1,x_2\)
\(\frac{\partial MRS}{\partial x_1} \le 0\) and \(\frac{\partial MRS}{ \partial x_2} \ge 0\), with at least one strict
MRS has no "jumps" (not defined piecewise)
Continuous
Utility function has no "jumps" (not defined piecewise)
(i.e., indifference curves get flatter as you move down and to the right)
Tangency condition: set MRS = price ratio
Constraint:
Two equations, two unknowns;
solve like you always have!
The Lagrange Method
Cost of Bundle X
Income
Utility
The Lagrange Method
Income left over
Utility
The Lagrange Method
Income left over
Utility
(utils)
(dollars)
utils/dollar
First Order Conditions
"Bang for your buck" condition: marginal utility from last dollar spent on every good must be the same!
The Lagrange Method
First Order Conditions
The Lagrange Method
Why use Lagrange?
1. It works for many goods.
2. The Lagrange multiplier has an
economic meaning (bang for your buck).
Next time: when Lagrange fails.....
Econ 50 | Spring 25 | Lecture 6
By Chris Makler
Econ 50 | Spring 25 | Lecture 6
Constrained optimization when calculus (the Lagrange method) works
- 269