Christopher Makler
Stanford University Department of Economics
Econ 51: Lecture 6
Bob has the Cobb-Douglas utility function \(u(x_1,x_2) = x_1x_2\) and an endowment of (8, 8)
Cobb-Douglas trick:
Since Bob has an endowment of (8,8), his "income" \(m\) is the value of that endowment
For this entire example, let's fix \(p_2 = 4\).
As we go through this example, work with a friend to solve it as well for Alison,
who has an endowment of (12,2).
The total quantity of a good
you want to consume (i.e. end up with)
at different prices.
The transaction you want to engage in
(the amount you want to buy or sell)
at different prices.
Bob has the Cobb-Douglas utility function \(u(x_1,x_2) = x_1x_2\) and an endowment of (8, 8)
When is this positive?
So, Bob wants to buy good 1 when \(p_1 < 4\), and sell it when \(p_1 > 4\).
Remember that his utility function is \(u(x_1,x_2) = x_1x_2\), his endowment is (8,8), and \(p_2 = 4\).
MRS at endowment =
Price ratio =
Bob's MRS at his endowment is
Bob's net demand is
Endowment: (8,8)
Utility function: \(u(x_1,x_2) = x_1x_2\)
Bob's gross demand for good 1 is:
Endowment: (12, 2)
Utility function: \(u(x_1,x_2) = x_1x_2\)
Alison's gross demand for good 1 is:
Alison's MRS at her endowment is:
Alison's net demand is:
...but where do they want to trade to?
What does the "lens" of overlap represent?
How is the existence of this lens related to
the agents' marginal rate of substitution (MRS) at point \(X\)?
Bob's MRS at his endowment is
Alison's MRS at her endowment is:
Alison wants to sell good 1 if:
Bob wants to buy good 1 if:
Between these two price ratios, Alison wants to sell good 1 and Bob wants to buy good 1.
Bob's gross demand for good 1 is:
Alison's gross demand for good 1 is:
Bob's gross demand for good 1 is:
Alison's gross demand for good 1 is:
His net demand for good 1 is:
Her net supply of good 1 is:
Bob demands 12
Alison supplies 2
Bob's gross demand for good 1 is:
Alison's gross demand for good 1 is:
His net demand for good 1 is:
Her net supply of good 1 is:
Bob demands 4
Alison supplies 4
Bob's gross demand for good 1 is:
Alison's gross demand for good 1 is:
His net demand for good 1 is:
Her net supply of good 1 is:
(Bob demands 0)
Alison supplies 5
Bob's net demand for good 1 is:
Alison's net supply of good 1 is:
Bob's net demand for good 1 is:
Alison's net supply of good 1 is:
Just like we always do, set these equal to one another and solve for the equilibrium price!
Bob's net demand for good 1 is:
Alison's net supply of good 1 is:
Just like we always do, set these equal to one another and solve for the equilibrium price!
The parameter \(a\) measures how much A likes good 1,
and the parameter \(b\) measures how much B likes good 1.
The parameter \(a\) measures how much A likes good 1,
and the parameter \(b\) measures how much B likes good 1.
Formula for the equilibrium price ratio:
In our example with Alison and Bob, we had: \(a = {1 \over 2}, e_1^A = 12, e_2^A = 2; b = {1 \over 2}, e_1^B = 8, e_2^B = 8\):
In this example, both Alison and Bob liked the two goods equally. Why wasn't the price ratio 1?
The parameter \(a\) measures how much A likes good 1,
and the parameter \(b\) measures how much B likes good 1.
Formula for the equilibrium price ratio:
What happens to the relative price of good 1
if people like good 1 more (that is, \(a\) and \(b\) are higher)?
What happens to the relative price of good 1
if there is more good 1 in the world (that is, \(e_1^A\) and \(e_1^B\) are higher)?
In competitive equilibrium in an exchange economy,
the price ratio reflects two fundamental things:
the preferences of the agents, and
the relative scarcity of the goods.
Since Anthony's preferred set is entirely on this set of the budget line...
...and Bruno's preferred set is entirely on this side of the budget line...
...then X* must be Pareto efficient!
[. ]
WHAT'S NEXT?