Production and Cost
for a Firm

Christopher Makler

Stanford University Department of Economics

Econ 50 : Lecture 13

pollev.com/chrismakler

How did the midterm go, relative to how you expected it to go?

So, about that test...

Remember that the purpose of this test was primary feedback:
reveal to yourselves where your understanding is squishy.

{MU_1 \over p_1} =
{MU_2 \over p_2} =
{3 \over 4}
{6 \over p_1}
{2 \over 3}
{MU_3 \over p_3} =

Key insight: you will only buy the good with the highest "boom for the buck" (i.e., \(MU/p\)).

What does this tell us about goods 2 and 3?

You will never buy good 2!

{MU_1 \over p_1} =
{3 \over 4}
{6 \over p_1}
{MU_3 \over p_3} =

Key insight: you will only buy the good with the highest "boom for the buck" (i.e., \(MU/p\)).

When will you only buy good 1?

{3 \over 4}
{6 \over p_1}
>

Key insight: you will only buy the good with the highest "boom for the buck" (i.e., \(MU/p\)).

When will you only buy good 1?

p_1 < 8
x_1^*(p_1)=\begin{cases}0 & \text{ if }p_1 > 8\\ [0,3] & \text{ if }p_1 = 8\\ {24 \over p_1} & \text{ if }p_1 < 8\end{cases}

Key insight: you will only buy the good with the highest "boom for the buck" (i.e., \(MU/p\)).

What happens if you try to equate the MU/p across goods (or equivalently, set the MRS's equal to the price ratios)?

{MU_1 \over p_1} =
{MU_2 \over p_2} =
{3 \over 4}
{6 \over p_1}
{2 \over 3}
{MU_3 \over p_3} =

About 48% of students approached that question
the correct way.

You are not alone.

Remember: the lower of your two midterm scores only counts for 10% of your grade.

If you get a 50 on the midterm (curved), you can still get as high as a 95% in the class.

But: if you struggled a lot on the test,
it means you should do something different about how you approach the class

The fact that so many of you strugged with a basic intuitive concept also means that I need to do something different about how I approach the class.

How class participation will count toward your grade

  • I will use PollEv to keep track of who has attended each lecture
  • If you do badly on an exam question, I will look to see if you missed class on the day related to that question.
  • If you were in class or had an excused absence*, I will add a few points back. If you just skipped class that day, I will have less sympathy.
  • So: you can still get 100% if you never come to class and ace all the exams; but if you do badly on an exam, showing that you were in class can help mitigate the damage.
  • *You may not have too many excused absences. (You can't just call in sick for the rest of the term.)

Today's Agenda

  • Review of Econ 1 Treatment of Production and Cost
  • Total, Average, and Marginal Costs
  • Long-Run Costs and Returns to Scale
  • Short-Run Costs and the Marginal Product of Labor

The Econ 1 Approach

Greg Mankiw, Principles of Economics

Greg Mankiw, Principles of Economics

Greg Mankiw, Principles of Economics

Greg Mankiw, Principles of Economics

Greg Mankiw, Principles of Economics

Dollars

Dollars Per Unit

Greg Mankiw, Principles of Economics

Total, Average, and Marginal Costs

Total Cost:

c(q) = 100,000

Average Cost:

{c(q) \over q} = {100,000 \over 200} = 500

Marginal Cost:

c'(q) = \text{probably pretty small}

Suppose it costs $100,000  to fly 200 passengers from SFO to NYC

Marginal cost tends to "pull" average cost toward it:

MC > AC \Rightarrow AC \text{ increasing}
MC = AC \Rightarrow AC \text{ constant}
MC < AC \Rightarrow AC \text{ decreasing}

Marginal grade = grade on last test, average grade = GPA

Relationship between Average and Marginal Costs

pollev.com/chrismakler

Suppose q* is the quantity
for which ATC is lowest.

Which of the following must be true?

(Assume that ATC and MC are continuous functions of q.)

(a) MC also reaches its minimum at q*

(b) MC reaches its maximum at q*

(c) MC and ATC are equal at q*

Long-Run Costs

Cost Minimization Subject to a Utility Constraint

Cost Minimization Subject to an Output Constraint

\min p_1x_1 + p_2x_2 \text{ s.t. } u(x_1,x_2) = U
\min wL + rK \text{ s.t. } f(L,K) = q
\text{solutions}: x_1^c(p_1,p_2,U), x_2^c(p_1,p_2,U)
\text{solutions}: L^c(w,r,q), K^c(w,r,q)

Hicksian Demand

Conditional Demand

Expansion Path

A graph connecting the input combinations a firm would use as it expands production: i.e., the solution to the cost minimization problem for various levels of output

Assuming the optimum is found via a tangency condition,
exactly the same as the tangency condition.

Long-Run Total Cost of \(q\) Units

c^{LR}(q) = wL^c(w,r,q) + rK^c(w,r,q)

Conditional demand for labor

Conditional demand for capital

"The total cost of producing \(q\) units in the long run
is the cost of the cost-minimizing combination of inputs
that can produce \(q\) units of output."

Exactly the same as the expenditure function in consumer theory.

Scaling Production

How does a technology respond to increasing production?

Short run: only some resources can be reallocated

Long run: all resources can be reallocated

It depends on the time horizon:

Scaling Production in the Long Run

What happens when we increase all inputs proportionally?

For example, what happens if we double both labor and capital?

Does doubling inputs -- i.e., getting \(f(2L,2K)\) -- double output?

f(2L,2K) > 2f(L,K)
f(2L,2K) = 2f(L,K)
f(2L,2K) < 2f(L,K)

Decreasing Returns to Scale

Constant Returns to Scale

Increasing Returns to Scale

f(L,K) = 4L^{1 \over 2}K

Does this exhibit diminishing, constant or increasing MPL?

Does this exhibit decreasing, constant or increasing returns to scale?

pollev.com/chrismakler

When does the production function

f(L,K) = AL^aK^b

exhibit constant returns to scale?

Relationship between Production Function and the Curvature of Long-Run Costs Functions

  • If the production function has decreasing returns to scale, the long-run cost curve will get steeper as you produce more output.
  • What about for constant returns to scale? Increasing returns to scale? 
  • Let's do a little bit of math on the board.

Short-Run Costs

Now assume that the level of capital is fixed in the short run at some amount \(\overline K\).

q = f(L\ |\ \overline K)

The amount of labor required to produce \(q\) units of output is therefore also going to depend upon \(\overline K\):

L(q\ |\ \overline K)

Scaling Production in the Short Run

Suppose \(K\) is fixed at some \(\overline K\) in the short run.
Then the production function becomes \(f(L\ |\ \overline K)\)

pollev.com/chrismakler

When does the production function

f(L) = 10L^a

exhibit diminishing marginal product of labor?

Short-Run Expansion Path

  • Shows how the firm's choice of labor and capital changes as it expands production.
  • If capital is fixed, what does this look like?

Short-Run Total Cost of \(q\) Units

TC(q\ |\ \overline{K}) = wL(q\ |\ \overline{K}) + r\overline{K}

Variable cost

"The total cost of producing \(q\) units in the short run is the variable cost of the required amount of the input that can be varied,
plus the fixed cost of the input that is fixed in the short run."

Fixed cost

f(L,K) = \sqrt{LK}

Short-run conditional demand for labor
if capital is fixed at \(\overline K\):

Total cost of producing \(q\) units of output:

L(q\ |\ \overline K) = {q^2 \over \overline K}
c(q\ |\ \overline{K}) = wL(q\ |\ \overline{K}) + r\overline{K} =
{wq^2 \over \overline K} + r\overline K

Total, Fixed and Variable Costs

c(q\ |\ \overline{K}) =

Fixed Costs \((F)\): All economic costs
that don't vary with output.

Variable Costs \((VC(q))\): All economic costs
that vary with output

explicit costs (\(r \overline K\)) plus
implicit costs like opportunity costs

r\overline{K}
wL(q,\overline{K})
+
TC(q) =
+
F
VC(q)

e.g. cost of labor required to produce
\(q\) units of output given \(\overline K\) units of capital

TC(q) = {wq^2 \over \overline K} + r\overline K
VC(q) = {wq^2 \over \overline K}
F = r\overline K

pollev.com/chrismakler

Generally speaking, if capital is fixed in the short run, then higher levels of capital are associated with _______ fixed costs and _______ variable costs for any particular target output.

\text{Total Cost}: TC(q) = F + VC(q)
\text{Average Cost}: ATC(q) = \frac{TC(q)}{q} = \frac{F}{q} + \frac{VC(q)}{q}

Fixed Costs

Variable Costs

Average Fixed Costs (AFC)

Average Variable Costs (AVC)

Average Costs

\text{Total Cost}: TC(q) = F + VC(q)
\text{Average Cost}: ATC(q) = \frac{F}{q} + \frac{VC(q)}{q}

Average Costs

TC(q) = 64 + {1 \over 4}q^2
ATC(q) = {64 \over q} + {1 \over 4}q
\text{Total Cost}: TC(q) = F + VC(q)
\text{Marginal Cost}: MC(q) = TC'(q) = 0 + VC'(q)

Fixed Costs

Variable Costs

Marginal Cost

(marginal cost is the marginal variable cost)

\text{Total Cost}: TC(q) = F + VC(q)
\text{Marginal Cost}: MC(q) = TC'(q)

Marginal Cost

TC(q) = 64 + {1 \over 4}q^2
MC(q) = {1 \over 2}q

Relationship between Marginal Cost and Marginal Product of Labor

TC(q) = wL^c(q | \overline K) + r \overline K
{dTC(q) \over dq} = w \times {dL^c(q) \over dq}
= w \times {1 \over MP_L}

Comparing the Short Run and the Long Run

Returns to a Single Input

  • Increasing marginal product: MPL is increasing in L
  • Constant marginal product: MPL is constant in L
  • Diminishing marginal product: MPL is decreasing in L

Returns to Scale (Scaling all inputs.)

  • Increasing returns to scale: doubling all inputs more than doubles output.
  • Constant returns to scale: doubling all inputs exactly doubles output.
  • Decreasing returns to scale: doubling all inputs less than doubles output.
f(L,K) = \sqrt{LK}

 Long Run (can vary both labor and capital)

L^c(q) = \sqrt{\frac{r}{w}}q
K^c(q) = \sqrt{\frac{w}{r}}q
TC^{LR}(q) = wL^c(q) + rK^c(q)
=2\sqrt{wr}q

 Short Run with Capital Fixed at \(\overline K \)

L^c(q | \overline K) = {q^2 \over \overline K}
TC(q) = wL^c(q | \overline K) + r \overline K
={wq^2 \over \overline K} + r \overline K
f(L,K) = \sqrt{LK}

 Long Run (can vary both labor and capital)

TC^{LR}(q)=2\sqrt{wr}q

 Short Run with Capital Fixed at \(\overline K \)

TC(q)={wq^2 \over \overline K} + r \overline K

Let's fix \(w= 8\), \(r = 2\), and \(\overline K =32\)

TC^{LR}(q)=8q
TC(q)=64 + {1 \over 4}q^2

Relationship between
Short-Run and Long-Run Costs

TC(q | \overline{K}) = \text{Cost if capital is fixed at }\overline{K}
TC(q,K^c(q)) = \text{Cost if capital is fixed at optimal }K \text{ for producing }q

What conclusions can we draw from this?

TC(q,\overline{K}) \ge TC^{LR}(q)
= TC^{LR}(q)
TC^{LR}(q) \text{ is the lower envelope of the family of }TC(q)\text{ curves}

Summary and Next Steps

  • Today: what happens as a firm scales up production in the short run and long run? How is that reflected in its cost curves?
  • Next time: short-run profit maximization, with and without market power
  • Monday: supply curve for a competitive firm